A proposal for a simplified fringe benefit tax regime for small businesses.

A proposal for a simplified fringe benefit tax regime for small businesses.

  • My guest this week is Claudia Siriwardena one of the four finalists for this year’s Tax Policy Charitable Trusts Scholarship.
  • We discuss her proposal for a simplified fringe benefit tax regime for small businesses.

My guest this week is Claudia Siriwardena, a tax consultant with Deloitte and another of the four finalists for this year’s Tax Policy Charitable Trust Scholarship competition.  The Tax Policy Charitable Trust was established by Tax Management New Zealand and its founder Ian Kuperus to encourage future tax policy leaders and support leading tax policy thinking in Aotearoa.

Claudia is suggesting a simplified fringe benefit tax regime for small businesses. I should make it clear here that everything in Claudia’s proposal and what is in this podcast represents her views and not those of Deloitte. Kia ora Claudia, welcome to the podcast. Thank you for joining us.

Claudia
Hi, Terry. Thanks very much for inviting me on.

Terry
Fringe benefit tax is a very controversial tax and one where there based on anecdote people seem to be shall we say, pushing the envelope.  I think the main controversy around fringe benefit tax is around the charge that’s that payable for the private use of public company vehicles.

That’s by far and away probably the largest single component of FBT’s and the advent of the twin cab ute, with people thinking that it qualifies for a work-related vehicle seems to have magnified the issues here. There was an Inland Revenue Stewardship Review of FBT a couple of years back and that had a lot of interesting stuff.

What caught your eye about FBT into thinking “Oh there’s something here to consider.”?

Claudia
Yes, like you say, Terry, it can be a very complex regime. There’s a lot of rules that that go into it and my initial inspiration for this simplified FBT regime came through my personal experience of undertaking tax due diligence. A common topic of discussion throughout tax due diligence is FBT, but particularly the FBT rules regarding motor vehicles provided to employees for private use.

I was thinking about ideas for the tax policy competition so I took that personal experience and I thought there was a real opportunity here to simplify these rules and to increase compliance. And aside from that, I think like you’ve said, there is a commonly held view that the FBT rules are relatively complicated and hard to understand. And that was something that was discussed in that Stewardship Review that you mentioned, and also a 2003 government discussion document. So what my proposal is intended to do is to simplify these rules and make it understandable.

A tax with a lot of non-compliance?

Terry
Yes, that Stewardship Review was very interesting, one of the numbers that interested me was that it raised $592 million for the 2019-20 year. But there are only 21,885 filers

When you think there’s several hundred thousand companies around, that does point to a seeming mismatch. I think also, like the old 80/20 rule, the majority of FBT is paid by a few groups. When you look at it like that, you think, gosh, that does point to something of an inconsistency? You can put it like that.

Claudia
Yes, totally agree. And I think throughout that sort of report, there’s a lot of comments in there from interviewees around non-compliance, or this perception that there is a lot of non-compliance.

Terry
Yes, because that undermines the integrity of the tax system because people feel that they’re complying with the rules, but others aren’t. Then the incentive to keep complying is diminished.

It wasn’t in the Stewardship Review, but I had seen other somewhat offhand comments from Inland Revenue along the lines of “Well, we don’t know if it’s worth our while doing that.”  And I always thought that’s not necessarily why you enforce the rules for collection purposes. It’s also about maintaining the integrity of the tax system.

And just to digress slightly, FBT is one of those regimes that was introduced to encourage compliance because with the high income tax rates in the early 80s, people were being provided with vehicles instead. And that was thought to bypass the high tax rates and that was why FBT was introduced in 1985.

How do you propose addressing these issues?

Claudia
The cornerstone of my proposal is introducing a default private use percentage for motor vehicles based on 175 days of private use. And the idea of this is essentially if employers apply this default private use percentage, they can use that to calculate the FBT liability. And then what it means is they don’t then have to go and track the actual days of private use. We can sort of cut down time and costs having to actually track all of that, because for a lot of small employers, that is quite a large exercise.  So what my proposal does is set a fixed percentage and apply that as the filing position.

And then obviously if people said, well, that’s not good enough for us, we want more accuracy because our use is lesser. They would then have to produce evidence or file on that basis. Inland Revenue would know they’ve moved off the 175 day default basis and then could ask for an explanation.

Terry
Just coming back to those 175 days, how did you arrive at that?

Claudia
So, the 175 days is calculated by treating Friday to Sunday of regular working weeks, the statutory annual leave entitlement and annual public holidays, as available for private use. Which in another way is essentially saying that Monday to Friday is treated as not being available for private use, and what I’ve done again for simply. What that does is it assumes that the Friday to Sunday of regular working weeks, your annual leave annual public holidays will typically confer a greater private benefit to employees then use on Monday to Thursday.

Terry
Thanks. But you wouldn’t change the basis of how FBT is calculated. To recap , quickly on a car, it’s 20% of the GST inclusive value of the vehicle when new or when acquired. Alternatively, you can use 36% of the depreciated tax book value.

Claudia
No, I don’t propose changing the basis of calculating FBT.

Terry
The availability of alternative calculations reinforces your point about the complexity of FBT. If you’re a small business, it’s another compliance headache.

Eligibility thresholds

Terry
Your proposal would not be available to all employers as you’re targeting smaller businesses. What are the relevant thresholds?

Claudia
I’ve got three main criteria. So firstly, the business has to employ less than 50 full time equivalent employees. The business has got to have an annual turnover of the preceding income year of less than $10 million. And the company also is providing fewer than 10 motor vehicles to employees, which were available for private use.

My thinking in terms of that criteria, is that the small businesses, the compliance costs that they incur, are typically out of proportion to the larger businesses.  So, what this is doing is focusing on smaller businesses who can actually get the most benefit from this, and who may not have sort of the processes in place or the scale of resources available to larger enterprises.

You’ve got to find some sort of threshold or middle ground. So, these criteria are where I landed in terms of deciding who falls in and out, because when we are considering revenue integrity and maintaining that. And what I don’t want is my proposal to then decrease revenue integrity by allowing, say, a lot more businesses than desirable into sort of this regime.

Increased Inland Revenue activity & the integrity of the tax system

Terry
You see your proposal as encouraging compliance, but you also expect Inland Revenue to increase its activity in this field?

Claudia
Yes, when you look at the Stewardship Review together with recent comments from the Minister of Revenue around FBT and you put that together with the increased funding that Inland Revenue have recently received in terms of audit activity, then I don’t really think anything is off the table in terms of looking at FBT. Especially when there is this common view that there is potentially non-compliance either intentionally or because of the complexity.

Terry
Yes, this is the thing it is all about.  Protecting the integrity of the tax system always matters but I think FBT is an area where I would have said a risk has developed. there. Do we know about how many companies that could be affected in your proposal?

Claudia
No, no, I haven’t come across that detail, which then also makes it quite hard to quantify potential impacts. But I think a lot of it this also goes back to the recent Inland Revenue Improvement Performance review which talks a bit about the tax gap. It doesn’t analyse what that FBT tax gap might be, which can make the benefit of this proposal quite hard to quantify.

Terry
That’s a very interesting point. One of the things I took away from the Performance Improvement Review was commentary that although Inland Revenue, is a high performing organisation it probably could be doing a lot better for small and micro businesses.

Just to tie up this point about non-compliance is I think twin cab utes have been in the top 10 selling new vehicles in New Zealand for several years now. I must admit when I see a web company advertising on a twin cab ute, I’m thinking “Don’t be trying to tell me you’re a work-related vehicle.” So yes, I’d be wanting to focus resources on that.

The pros and cons of simplifying the tax system

Earlier we talked about how you calculate the FBT and straight away we got into a lot of detail. I guess there’s got to be scope as well for perhaps thinking further about can we how can we make this easier?

But Inland Revenue is reluctant to create options that people might use for simplification, for fear that it might be abused. I would point to the accounting income method as an example of a good idea made over-complicated. It means that the same standard of compliance is imposed on a small company with two or three employees and one or two vehicles as for a District Health Board. What’s your thoughts on that? About maybe simplifying the regime further on the grounds of integrity and maybe compliance?

Claudia
I think general simplification of regimes is an interesting question and it definitely is the core of my proposal.  I think what can be good with simplified tax regimes is it just makes it understandable; it makes it simple which I think is really important for ensuring taxpayer compliance and maintaining that revenue integrity.

I think, for example, I’m not too sure how many clients respond positively when we start discussing the FBT rules, and we need to review this and that because it’s complicated.  On the other hand, a critique could be that you will lose revenue. Often with a simplified regime you sort of can strip back the detail, which is sort of what my default private use percentage is doing. But that potentially introduces is an under reporting or under collection of potential revenue.

But how I’ve sort of approached this, especially in the context of FBT and motor vehicles, is well, when you consider the current non-simplified regime is that actually losing revenue itself because of its complexity, because of people not complying? It’s a tricky one to balance and my proposal is definitely hoping that by simplifying the regime we increase compliance. I think it has its place in certain in certain regimes.

Terry
That’s very well put. I think sometimes the perfect is the enemy of the good. Everyone should comply, but what is making it difficult for everyone to comply is because for small businesses it’s an enormously expensive compliance burden. With compliance there is an irreducible minimum requirement which I think we’ve reached in many cases.  But that’s still a lot for small businesses and, micro businesses in particular.

I think a lot more support could be made available to businesses turning over between $3 and $30 million, and it would pay off in terms of increased compliance.

I come from Britain and the fringe benefit tax regime there, the value of the benefits, is included in an employee’s income at the end of the year and then taxed that way. When I came here and saw how New Zealand taxed fringe benefits I thought the approach here was much sounder in terms of revenue collection.

When you think that with a 39% personal income tax rate FBT is now 63.93% on the value of the benefit unless you get into calculating it in more detail. Have we reached a point that a better alternative for, say, larger companies to apply the fringe benefit to employees and tax it through PAYE rather than the company taking the hit. What’s your thoughts on that?

Claudia
Yes, when I was going through my initial process of brainstorming FBT issues and potential proposal ideas, I did consider the case of whether employees should bear different benefit tax costs through PAYE.

I think like you say, times have sort of moved on and they continue to, but based on some initial research that I found, it actually appeared that it was questionable whether making such a change would simplify the FBT regime and reduce compliance costs, which was my key focus.

I mentioned earlier the government discussion document from 2003. It noted that changing who pays the tax is unlikely to result in any material compliance savings for employers and may in fact actually increase compliance costs on employers.  

Which for my proposal and just in general, that’s not something that I would want to put forward. So, in this respect, who pays the tax doesn’t necessarily remove the issues that are associated with the FBT rules at present. So yes, noting that it was 2003, that’s probably still my view at the moment, based on that initial research.

Terry
I think that’s a good point to leave it there for now, Claudia. What’s next for you in terms of the scholarship?

Claudia
I’ve got my final 4000-word submission in a few weeks on the 16th of September. So over the next few weeks, refining my idea, sort of fleshing it out, answering my key points and then down to Wellington last week of October to do a 10 or 11 minute presentation to an audience and answer a few questions.

Terry
That sounds quite intimidating.

Claudia
Yes, but excited by it. It’ll be good fun.

Terry
Well, good luck and thank you so much for coming along. It’s been great to have you on the podcast. It’s a very interesting proposal, full of merit in a space which I think needs initiatives like this.

 And on that note, that’s all for this week. I’m Terry Baucher and you can find this podcast on my website www.baucher.tax or wherever you get your podcasts.  Thank you for listening and please send me your feedback and tell your friends and clients. Until next time, kia pai to rā. Have a great day.

COVID-19 related measures for tax losses and AirBnBs

  • COVID-19 related measures for tax losses and AirBnBs
  • National releases its small business policy
  • Is a capital gains tax back on the agenda?

Transcript

Friday was the due date for the first instalment of Provisional ax for the year ending 31st March 2021, Provisional tax is going to be payable by anyone whose net tax for this year will exceed $5,000.

Now in the past, we’ve covered the ability to use tax pooling to give more flexibility about payments of tax, and that’s going to be particularly important for the current tax year, given our ongoing uncertainties arising from the COVID-19 pandemic. My recommendation to clients at this moment is to adopt a conservative approach. Look at paying the first instalment of tax due today but keep watching your progress and how your turnover is going. And if matters move into a tax loss position as a downturn comes through soon, then we will take steps to mitigate or deal with the next two instalments of Provisional tax.

But what if you already know you’ve got losses this year and it’s not likely to get much better for the current year? Say you’re a restauranteur or you’re in the tourism business. These are two sectors which are very clearly hit hard by the pandemic and the various lockdown measures.

Well, one of the measures introduced as part of the government’s response to the pandemic was the ability to carry tax losses back. Under this measure, if you have a tax loss for the 2020 or 2021 income years, you can carry those losses back one year. And the idea is that if you carried back to a profitable year this will mean you have overpaid tax in the prior year, and that tax can be released to help smooth your time through this ongoing pandemic.

And for most larger companies the tax loss carry-back regime is pretty straightforward. Carry back the loss one year, get a tax refund at 28% percent, and then you’ve got funds, which you can either use to meet other bills you may be behind on, or bring it forward and apply it against your current tax year liabilities such as GST or PAYE, depending on how dire the situation might be.

But one of the problems that’s emerged with the tax loss carry back rules affects a lot of smaller companies where their shareholder is also an employee. And under the rules that apply to these companies, these companies can pay out their profits to a shareholder-employee who is then responsible for the tax.

For example, say a company makes a profit of $100,000.  Instead of paying tax at 28% it instead distributes it as a salary to a shareholder-employee and he or she is taxed on it at their relevant marginal rates. For someone on $100,000 with no other income, that roughly works out to about $24,000. So, there’s a tax benefit to shareholder-employees because of the gradual increase in tax rates for individuals.

But the problem that’s emerged wasn’t really addressed in the current legislation. What do you do if you carry a loss back for a company with a shareholder employee? The carried back loss is not much used to that particular company because they’ve already reduced their profit to nil by distributing it to the shareholder-employee.

And by the way, I note there was a Radio New Zealand report noting that about $2 billion dollars in wage subsidies has been paid to companies that do not appear to have paid any company income tax. It’s highly likely many of those companies have shareholder employees and it is the shareholder employee who has paid the tax using the mechanism I just explained where the whole or substantial amount of the company’s profit is paid out to the shareholder-employee.

So the tax loss carry back rules don’t work too well for small micro businesses that use a shareholder-employee mechanism. And it’s something we’ll need to be looked at if there is a permanent iteration of these rules, which I believe should happen.

But it’s also why the small business sector and accountants have not looked on this particular measure with a great deal of enthusiasm yet. Because of those complexities how do we deal with these tax losses that are brought back? Do you rewrite the whole position in the prior year? And then what does that do for other matters that are related to that person’s income, such as social assistance, ACC earner levies?  The amount of ACC you may claim if you have an accident is dependent on your salary as a shareholder-employee.

So, there’s a lot of complicated issues to work through. But the tax loss mechanism is there. It works very well for companies which don’t have shareholder-employees and individuals trading for themselves or trusts can use the loss carryback rules in either the 2020 or 2021 income years.

Converting from short-term to long-term rental accommodation.

Moving on, Airbnbs in the tourism sector will also have been hit very hard by the pandemic and the collapse in overseas tourism and the substantial decline in domestic tourism. So what has happened is some of these Airbnbs have reversed a trend that was developing, and have moved back into providing longer term residential accommodation.

As always, there’s a tax consequence to that and for GST purposes it means that if the GST activity is stopped, then the person is required to de-register for GST. Part of the de-registration process will mean a deemed supply of the goods that were brought into the business. You’re deemed to have sold them and pay GST output tax on the way out. And if you’ve claimed a big input tax credit for, say, a whole property, moving it over to Airbnb, that means that you could have a substantial output tax payable on de-registration, as it’s done at a market value.

Now, under the GST Act, there is a provision that where someone is no longer carrying on a taxable activity they are obliged to let the Commissioner of Inland Revenue know within 21 days of their taxable activity ceasing, and then that registration must be cancelled unless there are reasonable grounds to think the taxable activity will be carried on within 12 months. So, this could apply if you think that within 12 months-time, we could be back up and running again.

What Inland Revenue has done is extended this twelve-month period to 18 months through a special COVID-19 determination which has just been issued and this will apply until 30th September 2021. So you now have 18 months, a lot more flexibility about whether you’re going to resume your Airbnb activities or drop out of the picture completely.

Just a caveat though – if you are currently using a property for residential accommodation, but you anticipate going back to making taxable supplies in Airbnb, you have to do what’s called a change in use calculation.  This is basically an apportionment of the value of the property brought into the GST net over the expected time it’s being used for taxable activities. A little bit complicated, but you produce one of those calculations as part of your GST returns.

Political tax policy

Yesterday National released its small business tax policy.  In terms of tax rates it has come straight out and said it does not plan on increasing taxes or introducing any new taxes.

Other than tax rates, National’s tax policy has a number of other measures. Firstly, they’re going to lift the threshold for the purchase of new capital investment from $5,000 to $150,000 per asset. That is you can take a complete deduction for an asset costing up to $150,000. Now apparently this only applies to “productive assets” so there’s a question as to what that might mean.  It’s a temporary two-year change. Something similar has been done overseas.

And it’s a good idea although it is a question, of course, of what will and won’t meet the definition of ‘productive’. But you could see some fairly substantial plant and machinery being purchased and as a means of getting investment into productivity in the economy it’s a measure to be to be welcomed.

It would also have an impact on the Government’s cash flow, by the way, because it would drop quite a lot of people out of the provisional tax requirements. So the Government’s income, so to speak, was will be reduced temporarily before these payments will then come in at terminal tax time. I think $25,000 is too generous, $10,000 is probably manageable. Still it’s a measure in the right direction.

Next, they want to raise the GST threshold from $60,000 to $75,000. Big tick for that, the GST threshold hasn’t been increased since 1 April 2009. So it’s well overdue and on an inflation basis $75,000 is about right.

Businesses will be allowed to write off an asset once its depreciated value falls below $3,000 as opposed to continuing to depreciate it until its tax value reaches zero. Really good measure here. Should be done straightaway regardless of who’s in power.  Keeping a track of all these assets when they’ve fallen below that threshold is hard and causes needless complexity. So I like that a lot.

I also like this next one – change the timing of the second Provisional Tax payment for those with a 31 March balance date from 15th January to 28th February. That’s really quite sensible. It’s bizarre it’s in the middle of January when we’re all supposedly on holiday and it’s not a great time for cash flow. February makes a bit more sense.

Ensure the use of money interest rates charged by Inland Revenue more properly reflect appropriate credit rates. So right now, if you overpay your tax Inland Revenue will pay nothing. National are saying, well, we want something that’s a little bit more realistic than that. It’s not a bad move and it certainly would be popular with small businesses, but it’s rather based on an assumption that taxpayers would be using Inland Revenue as a bit of a bank. They won’t.  A better option in this case would be tax pooling which takes care of a lot of those issues.

Increase the threshold to obtain a GST tax invoice from $50 to $500. A very generous upper limit there. I’m not sure I’d go as high as that, but that $50 threshold below which you don’t need to have a full GST invoice with all the required details on it has not been changed since 28th September 1993. So an increase in the threshold is welcome. I’d say $150 might be a better option.

Implement a business continuity test rather than an ownership test for carry-forward of tax losses. Moves in this space are already happening but the measure is to be welcomed.

Next and also welcome, review depreciation rates for investments in energy efficiency and safety equipment. That’s not a bad idea. And then consolidate the number of depreciation rates to reduce  administration costs. That’s another big tick from me on that, because there are so many different rates and there’s options to probably get it wrong more often than right. And the level of micro detail required probably isn’t really appropriate for small businesses.

So those measures I think are mostly all welcome. And frankly, they’re sort of pretty much apolitical. Whoever is in power should be adopting almost all of those proposals.

Just a matter of time?

And finally, talking of parties’ tax policies, the Greens released as part of their tax policy, a proposal for a wealth tax to apply on net wealth over $1 million. Earlier this week, former legal practitioner, Human Rights Commissioner and retired Family Court Judge Graeme MacCormick picked up on the Green Party’s proposal when he wrote about the question of a wealth tax. He suggested a one percent levy on net assets of more than $10 million per person.

He also argued that it was time for the wealthy to step up and help out in this the crisis. He was sceptical of the idea of the trickle-down effect, that wealth trickles down and dissipates out through the country. He was of the view that basically we’ve got 30 years to show that hasn’t happened.

One of the interesting points he raised was that New Zealand not only doesn’t have a comprehensive capital gains tax, it also doesn’t have an estate tax or a gift tax nor a wealth tax. It’s highly unusual in the OECD for one jurisdiction to be not have at least one of those taxes applying on a comprehensive level. Some have capital gains tax and no wealth tax or estate tax. Others have a wealth tax, but no capital gains tax and some like the UK and the US, have capital gains taxes and estate and gift taxes.

The position varies across the OECD, but New Zealand is pretty unique in not having either a comprehensive capital gains tax, estate tax, gift duty or wealth tax.

Wealth taxes have fallen out of favour in the past few years, but they’re back on the agenda because, as I discussed with Radio New Zealand panel and Patrick Smellie of Business Desk, the pandemic and Thomas Piketty has opened the door on that.

And I was very interested to see this week that former Reserve Bank governor Dr Alan Bollard said in his presentation to the New Zealand CFO summit that, like it or not, given the scale of the borrowing the Government has had to engage in, capital gains tax may be an unpalatable option for governments to consider as they want to pay down the debt.

So this matter of capital taxation hasn’t gone away. We’ll hear more from other politicians no doubt, Labour and New Zealand First have still to release their tax policies. But we’ve still got another seven weeks to go to the election so there’s plenty of time for discussion on that.

Well, that’s it for this week. Thank you for listening. I’m Terry Baucher and this has been The Week in Tax. Please send me your feedback and tell your friends and clients until next week. Ka kite āno.